Of agricultural efficiency: the Vallis Veg mowing trial

Well, I lied to you. I said I was going to write a concluding post on the theme of the commons. But then I realised that this topic is kind of connected to a larger set of issues I’ve been wanting to explore about efficiency, scale, agrarian structures and the like. ‘Kind of connected’ is a useful phrase I picked up from an undergraduate lecture by one of my professors, Paul Richards (author of the brilliant Indigenous Agricultural Revolution…I wish I’d realised then how lucky I was to be taught by him). Paul said that on bad days it felt like the only conclusion he could come to about the world was that everything was kind of connected to everything else in complex ways that he couldn’t quite understand. And ain’t that ever so.

So I’m going to hold off on the conclusion to my commoning theme for a while, and work up to it more slowly and obliquely. Mind you, since introducing a ‘Donate’ button to my blog I suppose I do have a paying public to think about now. Let’s have a look at the account balance, then. Oh. OK, I’ll write what I damn well please…

Now then, Clem commented a couple of posts back on the issue of economies of scale in agriculture, and Brian Miller wrote an interesting post about farm energy and haymaking not so long ago. So let’s bring those themes together. Are there economies of scale in grass-cutting? My friend, I bring you the results of the official Vallis Veg mowing trial.

So, one bright June morning I spent a minute cutting grass with each of the following five increasingly scaled up mowing technologies available to me on my holding:

  1. With my bare hands
  2. With a 25cm hand sickle
  3. With a 50cm scythe (ditch blade)
  4. With a petrol-engine strimmer
  5. With a 5ft pasture topper attached to a 45hp diesel tractor

Only a minute, you say? Well, I’m a busy guy – besides, how long do you fancy pulling out perennial pasture grass with your bare hands?

And here are the results:

Area mown

My scythe isn’t the biggest and it wasn’t at its keenest, nor am I the best scythesman. Then again my tractor/topper aren’t the biggest either. But really there’s no two ways about it, the middle ages (scythe) beats the bronze age (sickle) by a factor of more than 4, and the industrial age (tractor) beats the middle ages by a factor of over 17. Comparing the tractor to bare hands, we could say there’s a labour efficiency factor of at least x132 with modern technology over no technology.

But let’s look at the energy inputs involved. Here I’m assuming a person eats 2,500 calories = 10.5 MJ per day, so I impute a minute’s portion of that daily intake to the operator in each case. Then there’s the embodied energy in the tools and machinery. Doubtless how to figure this in could be debated endlessly, but for simplicity I’ve taken a (probably now dated) standard figure for the per kg energy used in steel manufacture multiplied by the weight of the kit and the fraction of its expected working life devoted to the minute of grass cutting. Finally, I’ve added in the energy contained in the fuel used on the assumption that petrol and diesel contain about 36 MJ/l. I’m neglecting a lot of the other upstream costs of producing machinery and fossil fuel which probably biases the analysis in favour of the powered machinery, but there you go. Like I say, I’m a busy guy.

Here are the results:

Energy used

No surprises that the quicker the method of cutting the more gross energy it uses. The assumptions underlying my energy analysis are on an accompanying spreadsheet available from my Research and publications page. Of course, these assumptions are questionable, but I doubt any plausible set of alternatives would change the overall picture much. I’d be interested to know how a big modern tractor with a more efficient diesel engine would compare with my Ford 3600. Possibly it’d do a better job. On the embodied energy front I doubt that these tractors will still be plying their trade on small farms in forty years’ time as many of the Ford 3600 generation of tractors are, but since fuel use is the major factor, well…I guess one of those beasts could probably cut ten times the area of my rig in the same time, though it’d still probably use more fuel. How about plugging in these assumptions: compared to my tractor setup a big modern rig weighs four times more, cuts ten times more, uses double the fuel, and has a working life of 15 years working 2 days a week.

At any rate, let’s now put the two measures from the previous graphs together in a ratio:

Ratio area-energy

So, when it comes to energetic efficiencies of scale, the accolade goes to…the Middle Ages! Proof at last of what I’ve long argued on this site – a bit of technology is a wonderful thing, but the trick is knowing when to stop. The modern tractor rig assumptions improve the output/input ratio from 21 (my tractor) to 99 – only a little less efficient than using bare hands (110), but still eight times less efficient than the scythe.

OK, now I’m not seriously arguing that modern agriculture should dispense with its tractors and other powered machinery and return to the scythe…though I’m probably prepared to take that argument more seriously than most. Still, I think analyses like this do call into question the terms of the debate about agricultural efficiency or economies of scale. Modern mechanised agriculture has been labour ‘saving’, essentially by turbocharging traditional agricultural practices with the use of non-renewable and polluting fossil fuels. But it’s not especially efficient.

Now, if I were a mainstream economist, I’d probably just look at labour and fuel inputs as (relatively) substitutable factors of production. With agricultural diesel at 50p per litre and the minimum wage at £6.50 per hour the choice of grass-cutting method is a no brainer. I suppose if you figured in a sufficiently high carbon price as an externality it might change the picture a bit, but hey who cares about carbon pricing? Certainly not the governments of the world.

The problem with looking at labour and fuel inputs as substitutable factors of production is that it erases the politics and the history behind that simple 50p/l vs £7.50/hr choice. There’s a political and historical backstory here.

For proponents of agricultural ‘modernization’, the backstory is one of technological improvements releasing a grateful peasantry from backbreaking drudgery on the land (aside: in writings on agriculture, use of the word ‘backbreaking’ is a surefire signal that the virtues of Monsanto or John Deere are about to be extolled). For its opponents, the backstory is one of the deliberate separation of the working class from their means of subsistence on the land so they could be redeployed as industrial wage slaves. In both cases I think the narrative somewhat overstates the coherence of the process, which really emerged long-term from people responding to the more immediate incentives of the 50p/l vs £7.50/hr kind without being overly concerned about what kind of society (whether benevolent or malign) they were ultimately creating – though as David Graeber argues in his excellent tome Debt: The First 5000 Years, such responses themselves emerge from longer-term culture histories concerning money and exchange.

In any case, the modern result of these trends has been the creation of a pretty dysfunctional agricultural economy whose dominant tendencies involve substituting jobs with diesel wherever possible, paying less for food than its costs of production, shoring up the deficit for the lucky few rich farmers with government subsidies, pricing rural land beyond the means of ordinary people and ordinary farmers, and concentrating people in urban areas, where many experience chronic unemployment or underemployment, while the consequences of carbon emissions, soil loss etc are left to future generations to sort out, if they can.

Now, I’m not proposing so simple a solution to this mess as arming the un(der)employed urban masses with scythes and telling them to go cut something down (interesting, if alarming, as that process might be). Or banning tractors. I don’t think there are any simple solutions. But one way to move towards some complex solutions to these complex problems is to start telling some different and, yes, more complex stories about agriculture and its history and economics. And perhaps one of these stories, as per my grass cutting experiment, is to point out that agriculture is not more efficient, but less efficient than it used to be, at least according to one significant measure of agricultural performance. Perhaps you could still say that it’s more labour efficient, but wrapped up in that concept are a whole set of issues about the social organisation of labour, energy futures and so on. We need to be debating those issues openly, rather than erasing them by recourse to spurious notions of efficiency or idle conjectures about the future availability of limitless clean energy. I’m aiming to make my own particular contribution to that debate in this ongoing cycle of posts…

10 thoughts on “Of agricultural efficiency: the Vallis Veg mowing trial

  1. Hey Chris,
    interesting thoughts and great work overall!
    Perhaps you will be interested in a study on a small organic farm in Denmark and how it compares with Denmark as a whole across different indicators in terms of energy and emissions:

    “Sustainable Extensification as an Alternative Model For Reducing GHG Emissions From Agriculture. The Case of an Extensively Managed Organic Farm in Denmark” , online at:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/21683565.2015.1013240?src=recsys

    best,
    Jevgeniy

  2. Spending my lunch break working my way through your earlier posts.
    I’ve long thought that the biggest problem agriculture faces (and has faced for quite some time) is that in public discourse it is treated as a money making enterprise when, in fact, its an energy producing enterprise. Were modern farms being powered by horses the horses would all be dead because the farms produce less energy than they consume. Replace horses with undervalued fossil fuel energy and the farm becomes financially efficient.

    Thinking about farming in terms of energy efficiency wouldn’t necessarily preclude the use of fossil fuel energy. There may be places and tasks for which it would be appropriate. I’d be interested in seeing Chris’ energy efficiency ratios for ploughing or for some forestry work. Although might take us to a reshaping of agricultural and forestry practice that is less energy dependent.

    Given that so many of the problems we face (climate change, rampant consumerism, environmental destruction, I’d even add rising inequality to this list) seem to stem from our use/misuse and control of (fossil fuel) energy perhaps the solution would be a monetary system underpinned by energy. A watt is a watt is a watt regardless of how generated.

  3. Hello Hello.
    I just wrote a post on our bosquihermanos blog, about why I prefer to use the scythe before any other method to mow …
    I wonder if I can include your graphics and a link to your post.
    Thank you and sorry for the English I use. I’m using google translate, I know I’m good but the languages are not my thing.
    A greeting.
    Ramón.

  4. Working my way back in your post I read this one. Agree fully with the abuse of “efficiency” and “productivity” in the modern agriculture narrative.

    We need to redefine productivity. But it is not sufficient to theoreti­cally redefine productivity, we also need to redesign the economic system which has created a distorted view of what is productive and what is not. Today, productivity is measured by how many trees one person can cut down with her chainsaw or how much fish a fisherman can scoop up from the sea. But as natural resources dwindle, the real productivity lies in how these resources re-generate. We are produc­tive if there is more forest next year than today, if there are more fish and if the soil becomes more fertile by the years instead of being exhausted and eroded. In a similar way we are efficient if the food we produce and consume is healthy rather than if it is cheap.

    I expand on this here: http://gardenearth.blogspot.se/2016/11/efficiency-and-productivity-two-very.html

    • Thanks for that, Gunnar. I like your idea of efficiency in terms of leaving as much as you take. Perhaps, strictly, this isn’t ‘efficiency’ but a measure of stock. But then in that case the importance of ‘efficiency’ needs to be demoted. First we decide how to organise the economy – and stock maintenance would inevitably loom large here. Then we figure out how best to do it, bearing efficiency in mind. But ‘efficiency’ is a second-order means issue, never an end.

      • Not sure whether this actually speaks to the efficiency/productivity conundrum, but should we not also consider values – relative values in particular? Value is a VERY subjective concept at the individual level. And the value of one resource to person A will likely be different than the value of a second resource to the same individual. Add to the mix a second person (B) whose sense of the relative values will be different. If these two interact and negotiate their individual likes/tastes for these resources the subjectivity slips a tiny bit. Add more and more people to the mix, consider different resources, and the matrix of interactions multiplies. The level of subjectivity slips as the number of opinions increases. Right now we organize markets to find prices (market price being a less subjective proxy for value) and I’ll go so far as to suggest the market price is the most objective signal for value we’ve currently constructed.

        We can value productivity and efficiency in some ways – but the most objective means involves surveying the largest audiences. Where small samples are surveyed, the value paradigm will be more heavily biased by the subjective notions of the individuals involved. From all that I get the sense a Small Farm Future will also necessarily be a Small Community Future. And even the notion of Small ends up being subject to, well, subjective interpretation.

        Lots of folks value large. And economies of scale work against smaller operations. Moving against both a large population’s opinion and the scale phenomenon makes the ‘scale’ of the problem serious. But hey, if it were easy, everyone would have a solution.

        • Clem, I’d like to respond to your comment, but I’m lacking in time really. You’ve put together a respectable line of reasoning with your customary eloquence…but it’s one I disagree with in various rather fundamental ways. I’d want to put together an alternative line of reasoning based on contentions like (1) beyond the trivialities of personal taste, values are not highly individual but fundamentally collective/cultural/ideological (2) western culture in modern times has placed a lot of emphasis on individual values realised in monetised markets, but this itself is a cultural value – so in some ways the idea that the market is the most objective signal for value is a self-fulfilling prophecy, or indeed a value in itself (3) in a relatively closed local agrarian society I’d agree that prices give useful and quasi-objective signals to would-be entrants – should I produce eggs or table chickens etc. – but open global markets don’t do so. If they did, they’d have sorted out an issue like climate change long ago, rather than compounding it (4) given various initial conditions, there certainly can be economies of large scale (there can also be diseconomies of large scale), but the initial conditions are never endogenous, they never simply ‘are’, they’re always ultimately a political choice, a value, and not the only one possible (5) Lots of folks may value large, but it’s almost impossible to determine what that means without a wider historical understanding of their cultural and economic grounding. Supposing it’s true that most people ‘value large’, I don’t think you can derive an ought (‘large is good’) from that is (‘large is popular’).

          Sorry I don’t have the time to put that into a more cogent argument…perhaps there’s scope for a future post there.

  5. You’re missing the middle ground of technology between the scythe and the 4 wheel tractor, demonstrating E. F. Schumacher’s “‘law of the disappearing middle”. The walking tractor with sickle bar is still popular in hilly Italy and Switzerland and making something of a comeback on small farms here in the States:
    https://earthtoolsbcs.com/implements-mowing/cutterbarmowers/
    There’s even a disc mower:
    https://earthtoolsbcs.com/implements-mowing/discmowers/
    I expect it would fall somewhere between the scythe and the tractor in productivity of time and fuel.

    • At the time I did the trial I didn’t have any intermediate technology between the strimmer and the topper. I do now have access to a walking tractor mower so perhaps I’ll re-run it to include it. My guess is that it’ll fall between the tractor and the strimmer. It’s a useful beast, though.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *